Vocapedia >
Language >
Argumentation
Adverbs, adjectives, conjunctions,
modals, nouns, phrases
Freshly Squeezed
by Ed Stein
GoComics
January 12, 2014
http://www.gocomics.com/freshlysqueezed#.UtJMzvTuK_8
to begin with, ...
to start,
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/08/28/opinion/l28food.html
I agree
with...
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/11/28/opinion/l28friedman.htm
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/08/28/opinion/l28food.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/07/03/opinion/l03crime.html
disagree
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/02/10/opinion/l10precious.html
I
disagree that...
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/08/28/
opinion/l28food.html
argue
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/06/01/opinion/l01nuke.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/10/opinion/10collins.html
,some might
argue,
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/11/11/nyregion/11cuomo.html
It can be
argued that ...
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/11/23/us/23land.html
it could
be argued that ...
it needs to
be recognized that ...
we need to ...
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/11/28/opinion/l28friedman.html
I couldn’t
help but wonder:
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/12/01/opinion/01friedman.html
It’s no wonder
then that...
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/18/opinion/18blow.html
I think it
is fair to say...
I mean to
be honest...
it is nothing
short of...
the point is...
let me
stress this...
let me
be clear
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/18/opinion/18blow.html
just let me
finish the point
I'm absolutely
clear that...
want to
make it clear that...
http://www.guardian.co.uk/books/2010/may/22/christopher-hitchens-decca-aitkenhead
It seems obvious
to me that...
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/06/29/opinion/l29afghan.html
Are
you
saying that... ?
needless to say
http://www.independent.co.uk/news/people/profiles/
jean-nouvel-good-for-a-prize-but-not-for-a-prince-2023805.html
given that...
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/12/26/opinion/l26elite.html
whether you like
it or not
hang on
just a second
I’ll grant Mr.
Budiansky that...
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/08/28/opinion/l28food.html
granted, ... even so, ...
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/05/25/opinion/25gyatso.html
even so,
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/12/31/opinion/31fri1.html
sure
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/18/opinion/18blow.html
you know
https://www.npr.org/2021/11/19/
1057407163/house-democrats-pass-bidens-social-programs-bill
Let
me get this straight
https://www.npr.org/2017/07/27/
537309087/first-listen-randy-newman-dark-matter
first,
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/21/opinion/21brooks.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/05/09/opinion/l09immig.html
second,
http://www.nytimes.com/2013/06/04/opinion/brooks-the-way-to-produce-a-person.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/21/opinion/21brooks.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/05/09/opinion/l09immig.html
Third, and most important,
http://www.nytimes.com/2013/06/04/
opinion/brooks-the-way-to-produce-a-person.html
let's
talk about ...
we'll have to
see, won't we
issue
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/10/opinion/10collins.html
raise the issue
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/02/17/world/middleeast/17clinton.html
it raises the
question:
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/11/22/opinion/22rubin.html
debate
right
wrong
this is wrong and
unacceptable
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/11/30/opinion/30krugman.html
don’t
get me wrong
http://www.nytimes.com/2011/01/03/opinion/03cole.html
fair
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/10/opinion/10collins.html
unfair
of course
obviously
true
It is definitely
true that...
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/10/opinion/10collins.html
untrue
relevant
irrelevant
http://www.guardian.co.uk/books/2009/jan/23/teacher-proclaims-twain-lee-steinbeck-irrelevant
http://www.guardian.co.uk/politics/2005/jul/29/labour.politicalcolumnists
in fact,
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/10/26/opinion/26brooks.html
in short,
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/10/26/opinion/26brooks.html
indeed
http://ethicist.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/11/03/must-you-vote/
as a result,
http://www.nytimes.com/2013/12/27/opinion/krugman-the-fear-economy.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/01/20/us/politics/20assess.html
as he said...
as the saying goes,
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/18/opinion/18blow.html
so
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/25/opinion/25krugman.html
if so
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/25/opinion/25krugman.html
if
That is a big if.
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/07/us/politics/07obama.html
so far
so as to
to
in order to
overall
on the one hand,
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/12/17/opinion/17brooks.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/10/26/opinion/26brooks.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/24/opinion/24brooks.html
one one hand,
http://blogs.reuters.com/chrystia-freeland/2011/02/11/when-the-hacker-ethos-meets-capitalism/
on the other hand,
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/12/17/opinion/17brooks.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/24/opinion/24brooks.html
http://www.guardian.co.uk/world/2009/sep/10/second-world-war-battle-bulge
to some extent
in some respects,
http://www.nytimes.com/2013/12/21/world/middleeast/yemen-
deaths-raise-questions-on-new-drone-policy.html
still
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/11/03/opinion/03zandi.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/29/opinion/29thu1.html
however
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/07/opinion/07tue1.html
yet
as yet
as
as I said...
as ... as
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/25/opinion/25krugman.html
as for...
so far as...
as far as I am
concerned
as far as I know
as you
know
I am all too aware
of...
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/06/05/opinion/l05oil.html
most of all
far and away
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/news/business/companies/youtube/index.html
I have to
say
this being said
that said,
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/08/28/opinion/l28food.html
I believe
I do believe
believe it or not,
regardless of what...
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/18/opinion/18blow.html
instead
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/25/opinion/25krugman.html
instead of...
at least
inasmuch
http://community.nytimes.com/comments/www.nytimes.com/2009/09/05/opinion/05herbert.html
as well as
as well
also
bear in mind also
...
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/12/18/opinion/18krugman.html
too
again
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/12/18/opinion/18krugman.html
and
even
even if
even though
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/06/29/opinion/l29afghan.html
even as
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/28/opinion/28krugman.html
as though
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/05/world/asia/05afghan.html
if
whether
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/10/opinion/10collins.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/05/opinion/05mon1.html
then
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/25/opinion/25krugman.html
first
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/25/opinion/25krugman.html
the first thing to say is...
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/12/08/opinion/08brooks.html
it is quite
remarkable that...
second
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/25/opinion/25krugman.html
thus
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/25/opinion/25krugman.html
therefore
like
unlike
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/12/15/opinion/l15health.html
on the contrary
quite the contrary
http://www.nytimes.com/2013/12/14/
opinion/macmillan-the-great-wars-ominous-echoes.html?pagewanted=2
contrary topréposition
N
http://www.guardian.co.uk/culture/2009/nov/29/
borders-bookshops-independent-lutyens-rubinstein
how does it
compare topréposition
N ?
http://www.guardian.co.uk/news/datablog/2009/sep/29/
gordon-brown-speech-peter-mandelson-labour-conference
but
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/25/opinion/25krugman.html
But don’t
mistake ... for ...
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/08/28/opinion/l28food.html
by contrast
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/10/17/business/17view.html
as
It’s not because
... It's because
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/08/28/opinion/l28food.html
for example
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/12/26/opinion/l26elite.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/10/26/opinion/26brooks.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/28/opinion/28krugman.html
for instance
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/12/26/opinion/l26elite.html
such
no such
such as
as such,
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/07/opinion/07tue1.html
what is more
moreover
furthermore
plus
on top of that
above all
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/12/26/opinion/l26elite.html
additionally
nevertheless
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/21/opinion/21herbert.html
nonetheless
despite
so it comes as no
surprise that,
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/07/04/technology/04ping.html
for all of the...
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/27/opinion/27sun1.html
underscore
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/12/12/opinion/l12nobel.html
underline
highlight
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/05/world/asia/05afghan.html
emphasize
point out
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/02/09/opinion/l09deficit.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/10/opinion/10collins.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/05/opinion/05adouthat.html
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/28/opinion/28krugman.html
I think I
would make two points
however
stress
needless to say
, say,
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/28/opinion/28krugman.html
strictly speaking
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/28/opinion/28krugman.html
by the way
this time around, though,
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/12/25/world/europe/25start.html
although
albeit
while
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/10/opinion/10collins.html
whereas
rather than + BV /
-ing
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/11/26/opinion/l26digital.html
http://www.guardian.co.uk/environment/2009/oct/15/which-survey-electric-recycling
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/28/opinion/28krugman.html
claim
claim
mean
meaning
meaningful
meaningless
to conclude
as a conclusion
in conclusion
it is not a
foregone conclusion
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/18/opinion/18blow.html
to put it briefly
(to put it) in a
nutshell USA
http://www.nytimes.com/2011/09/17/opinion/nocera-killing-jobs-and-making-us-sick.html
last but not least USA
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/10/26/arts/26iht-design26.html
to sum up
let me
sum up
Corpus of news articles
Vocapedia > Language > Argumentation
Adverbs, adjectives, conjunctions,
modals, nouns, phrases
The Fear Economy
December 26, 2013
The New York Times
By PAUL KRUGMAN
More than a million unemployed Americans are about to get the
cruelest of Christmas “gifts.” They’re about to have their unemployment benefits
cut off. You see, Republicans in Congress insist that if you haven’t found a job
after months of searching, it must be because you aren’t trying hard enough.
So you need an extra incentive in the form of sheer desperation.
As a result, the plight of the unemployed, already terrible, is about to
get even worse. Obviously those who have jobs are much better off. Yet
the continuing weakness of the labor market takes a toll on them, too. So
let’s talk a bit about the plight of the employed.
Some people would have you believe that employment relations are just like any
other market transaction; workers have something to sell, employers want to buy
what they offer, and they simply make a deal. But anyone who has ever held a job
in the real world — or, for that matter, seen a Dilbert cartoon — knows that
it’s not like that.
The fact is
that employment generally involves a power relationship: you have a boss, who
tells you what to do, and if you refuse, you may be fired. This doesn’t have to
be a bad thing. If employers value their workers, they won’t make unreasonable
demands. But it’s not a simple transaction. There’s a country music
classic titled “Take This Job and Shove It.” There isn’t and won’t be a song
titled “Take This Consumer Durable and Shove It.”
So employment is a power relationship, and high unemployment has greatly
weakened workers’ already weak position in that relationship.
We can actually
quantify that weakness by looking at the quits rate — the percentage of
workers voluntarily leaving their jobs (as opposed to being fired) each month.
Obviously, there are many reasons a worker might want to leave his or her job.
Quitting is, however, a risk; unless a worker already has a new
job lined up, he or she doesn’t know how long it will take to find a new job,
and how that job will compare with the old one.
And the risk of quitting is much greater when unemployment is high, and there
are many more people seeking jobs than there are job openings. As a result,
you would expect to see the quits rate rise during booms, fall during slumps —
and, indeed, it does. Quits plunged during the 2007-9 recession, and they have
only partially rebounded, reflecting the weakness and inadequacy of our economic
recovery.
Now think about what this means for workers’ bargaining power. When the
economy is strong, workers are empowered. They can leave if they’re unhappy with
the way they’re being treated and know that they can quickly find a new job if
they are let go. When the economy is weak, however, workers have a very weak
hand, and employers are in a position to work them harder, pay them less, or
both.
Is there any evidence that this is happening? And how. The economic recovery
has, as I said, been weak and inadequate, but all the burden of that weakness is
being borne by workers. Corporate profits plunged during the financial crisis,
but quickly bounced back, and they continued to soar. Indeed, at this point,
after-tax profits are more than 60 percent higher than they were in 2007, before
the recession began. We don’t know how much of this profit surge can be
explained by the fear factor — the ability to squeeze workers who know that they
have no place to go. But it must be at least part of the explanation. In fact,
it’s possible (although by no means certain) that corporate interests are
actually doing better in a somewhat depressed economy than they would if we had
full employment.
What’s more, I
don’t think it’s too much of a stretch to suggest that this reality helps
explain why our political system has turned its backs on the unemployed. No, I
don’t believe that there’s a secret cabal of C.E.O.’s plotting to keep the
economy weak. But I do think that a major reason why reducing unemployment isn’t
a political priority is that the economy may be lousy for workers, but corporate
America is doing just fine.
And once you understand this, you also understand why it’s so
important to change those priorities.
There’s been a somewhat strange debate among progressives lately, with some
arguing that populism and condemnations of inequality are a diversion, that full
employment should instead be the top priority. As some leading
progressive economists have pointed out, however, full employment is
itself a populist issue: weak labor markets are a main reason workers are losing
ground, and the excessive power of corporations and the wealthy is a main reason
we aren’t doing anything about jobs.
Too many Americans currently live in a climate of economic fear. There are many
steps that we can take to end that state of affairs, but the most
important is to put jobs back on the agenda.
The Fear Economy,
NYT,
26.12.2013,
http://www.nytimes.com/2013/12/27/opinion/krugman-the-fear-economy.html
Safer
Social Security
November
14, 2010
The New York Times
By PETER ORSZAG
Social
Security is not the key fiscal problem facing the nation. Payments to its
beneficiaries amount to 5 percent of the economy now; by 2050, they’re projected
to rise to about 6 percent. Over the same period, federal health care costs will
increase six times as much.
Nevertheless, Social Security does face an actuarial deficit. Current
projections suggest that, after 2037, benefits would need to be reduced by more
than 20 percent to match revenue. Measured over the next 75 years, the deficit
in Social Security is expected to amount to 0.7 percent of the economy — not a
huge amount, but a deficit nonetheless.
So it would be desirable to put the system on sounder financial footing.
And that is precisely what the co-chairmen of President Obama’s bipartisan
commission on reducing the national debt have bravely proposed to do. It’s too
bad their proposal has been greeted with so much criticism, especially from
progressives — who really should look at it as an opportunity to fix Social
Security without privatizing it. Although the plan leans too much on future
benefit reductions and not enough on revenue increases, it still offers a good
starting point for reform.
The proposal put forward last week by Alan Simpson, the former Senate Republican
leader, and Erskine Bowles, who was a White House chief of staff under President
Bill Clinton, has four main elements.
First, it would make the payroll tax more progressive by increasing the
maximum earnings level to which it applies. Over the past several decades, as
higher earners have enjoyed particularly rapid wage gains, a growing share of
their wages has escaped the tax because they have been above the maximum taxable
level. Today, about 15 percent of total wages are not taxed. The chairmen
recommend gradually raising the maximum threshold so that, by 2050, only 10
percent of total wages wouldn’t be taxed — decreasing the 75-year Social
Security deficit by more than a third.
Second, Mr. Simpson and Mr. Bowles recommend indexing the age at which
full Social Security benefits can be received to increases in life expectancy.
This age is already increasing to 67, and under the proposal the gradual rise
would continue, to 68 by 2050. A better approach would be to leave the full
benefit age alone and instead directly reduce the monthly benefits as life
expectancy rises, to keep average lifetime benefits roughly constant. But the
chairmen’s approach would by itself narrow the Social Security gap by about a
fifth.
The third suggested change is to make the formula for determining Social
Security benefits more progressive, by reducing future payments to high earners
while increasing them for people at the bottom. These adjustments would close at
least another third of the projected deficit. And they would also help offset a
little-noticed trend: affluent Americans are increasingly living longer than
others. This pushes the Social Security system toward being less progressive, as
higher earners collect benefits for more years.
Finally, Mr. Bowles and Mr. Simpson would have Congress adjust the
cost-of-living index that’s used to determine annual increases in Social
Security benefits so that it would measure inflation more accurately. Making
this switch would fill in more than a quarter of the long-term deficit, because
the new index would grow more slowly.
If Congress were to take all four of these recommended steps, it could not
only eliminate the long-term deficit in Social Security but also make
the system much more progressive. Even compared with the benefits
promised by the current system, the recommended benefits for the poorest 20
percent of recipients would increase by about 5 percent, while those for
the wealthiest retirees would fall by almost 20 percent.
Furthermore, the plan would not create private accounts within Social
Security — the most controversial issue that came up when reform was last
debated in 2005. Why not lock in a reform when private accounts are off the
table? (Note to progressives: the Social Security plan put forward by Paul Ryan
of Wisconsin, the expected new chairman of the House Budget Committee, does
include private accounts.)
The main flaw in the proposed Social Security plan is that it relies too little
on revenue increases and too much on future benefit reductions. A reasonable
objective would be a 50-50 balance between changes in benefits and changes in
revenues. But the way to bring reform into better proportion is to adjust the
components of this proposal, not to fundamentally remodel it.
Finally, even though Social Security is not a major contributor to our
long-term deficits, reforming it could help the federal government establish
much-needed credibility on solving out-year fiscal problems — which in turn
could improve the political prospects for providing additional short-term
stimulus for the economy. All of which suggests that Democrats in Congress
should support the basic construct of the Bowles-Simpson proposal, while arguing
for some changes to improve it. That has not, however, been their reaction thus
far.
It is therefore crucial that the Obama administration recognize the
opportunity and respond to it more positively. The White House has been handed a
highly progressive reform plan for Social Security that could attract Republican
support as well.
Peter Orszag,
the director of the White House Office
of Management and Budget from 2009 to
2010
and a distinguished visiting fellow
at the Council on Foreign Relations,
is
a contributing columnist for The Times.
Safer Social Security, NYT, 14.11.2010,
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/11/15/opinion/15orszag.html
Op-Ed Columnist
Cassandras of Climate
September 28, 2009
The New York Times
By PAUL KRUGMAN
Every once in a while I feel despair over the fate of the planet.
If you’ve been following climate science, you know
what I mean: the sense that we’re hurtling
toward catastrophe but nobody wants to hear about it or do anything to avert it.
And here’s the thing: I’m not engaging in hyperbole. These days, dire warnings
aren’t the delusional raving of cranks. They’re what come out of the most widely
respected climate models, devised by the leading researchers. The prognosis for
the planet has gotten much, much worse in just the last few years.
What’s driving this new pessimism? Partly it’s the fact that some predicted
changes, like a decline in Arctic Sea ice, are happening much faster than
expected. Partly it’s growing evidence that feedback loops amplifying the
effects of man-made greenhouse gas emissions are stronger than previously
realized. For example, it has long been understood that global warming
will cause the tundra to thaw, releasing
carbon dioxide, which will cause even more warming, but new research shows far
more carbon dioxide locked in the permafrost than previously thought, which
means a much bigger feedback effect.
The result of all this is that climate scientists have, en masse, become
Cassandras — gifted with the ability to prophesy future disasters, but
cursed with the inability to get anyone to believe them.
And we’re not just talking about disasters in the distant future,
either. The really big rise in global temperature probably won’t take place
until the second half of this century, but there will be plenty of damage long
before then.
For example, one 2007 paper in the journal Science is titled “Model
Projections of an Imminent Transition to a More Arid Climate in Southwestern
North America” — yes, “imminent” — and reports “a broad consensus among climate
models” that a permanent drought, bringing Dust Bowl-type conditions, “will
become the new climatology of the American Southwest within a time frame of
years to decades.”
So if you live in, say, Los Angeles,
and liked those pictures of red skies and choking dust in Sydney, Australia,
last week, no need to travel. They’ll be coming your way in the not-too-distant
future.
Now, at this point I have to make the obligatory disclaimer that no
individual weather event can be attributed to global warming.
The point,
however, is that climate change will make events like that Australian dust
storm much more common.
In a rational world, then, the looming climate disaster would be our
dominant political and policy concern. But it manifestly isn’t. Why not?
Part of the answer is that it’s hard to keep
peoples’ attention focused. Weather fluctuates — New Yorkers
may recall the heat wave that pushed the
thermometer above 90 in April — and even at a global level, this is enough to
cause substantial year-to-year wobbles in average temperature. As a result, any
year with record heat is normally followed by a number of cooler years:
According to Britain’s Met Office, 1998 was the hottest year so far, although
NASA — which arguably has better data — says it was 2005. And it’s all too easy
to reach the false conclusion that the danger is past.
But the larger reason we’re ignoring climate change is that Al Gore was
right: This truth is just too inconvenient. Responding to climate change with
the vigor that the threat deserves would not, contrary to legend, be devastating
for the economy as a whole. But it would
shuffle the economic deck, hurting some powerful vested interests even
as it created new economic opportunities. And the industries of the past
have armies of lobbyists in place right now; the industries of the future don’t.
Nor is it just a matter of vested interests.
It’s also a matter of vested ideas. For three decades the dominant
political ideology in America has extolled private enterprise and denigrated
government, but climate change is a problem that
can only be addressed through
government action. And rather than
concede the limits of their philosophy, many on
the right have chosen to deny that the
problem exists.
So here we are, with the greatest challenge
facing mankind on the back burner, at best, as a policy issue. I’m not, by
the way, saying that the Obama administration was wrong to push health care
first. It was necessary to show voters a tangible achievement before next
November. But climate change legislation had better be next.
And as I pointed out in my last
column, we can afford to do this. Even as
climate modelers have been reaching consensus on the view that the threat is
worse than we realized, economic modelers have been reaching consensus on the
view that the costs of emission control are lower than many feared.
So the time for action is now. O.K., strictly speaking it’s long past.
But better late than never.
Cassandras of Climate,
NYT, 28.9.2009,
http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/28/opinion/28krugman.html
Op-Ed Columnist
It’s Easy Being Green
September 25, 2009
The New York Times
By PAUL KRUGMAN
So, have you enjoyed the debate over health care reform?
Have you been impressed by the civility of the discussion and the intellectual
honesty of reform opponents?
If so, you’ll love the next big
debate: the fight over climate change.
The House has already passed a fairly strong cap-and-trade climate bill, the
Waxman-Markey act, which if it becomes law would
eventually lead to sharp reductions in
greenhouse gas emissions. But on climate change, as on health care, the
sticking point will be the Senate. And the
usual suspects are doing their best to prevent action.
Some of them still claim that there’s no such thing as global warming, or
at least that the evidence isn’t yet conclusive. But that argument
is wearing thin — as thin as the
Arctic pack ice, which has now diminished to the point that shipping companies
are opening up new routes through the formerly impassable seas north of Siberia.
Even corporations are losing patience with the deniers: earlier this week
Pacific Gas and Electric canceled its membership in the U.S. Chamber of Commerce
in protest over the chamber’s “disingenuous attempts to diminish or distort the
reality” of climate change.
So the main argument against climate action probably
won’t be the claim that global warming is a
myth. It will, instead, be the argument that doing anything to limit global
warming would destroy the economy. As the blog Climate Progress puts it,
opponents of climate change legislation “keep raising their estimated cost of
the clean energy and global warming pollution reduction programs like some out
of control auctioneer.”
It’s important, then, to understand that claims of immense economic
damage from climate legislation are as bogus, in their own way, as
climate-change denial. Saving the planet won’t come
free (although the early stages of conservation actually might). But it
won’t cost all that much either.
How do we know this? First, the evidence suggests that we’re wasting a
lot of energy right now. That is, we’re burning large amounts of coal, oil and
gas in ways that don’t actually enhance our standard of living — a phenomenon
known in the research literature as the “energy-efficiency gap.” The existence
of this gap suggests that policies promoting energy conservation
could, up to a point, actually
make consumers richer.
Second, the best available economic analyses suggest that even deep cuts
in greenhouse gas emissions would impose only modest costs on the average
family. Earlier this month, the Congressional Budget Office released an analysis
of the effects of Waxman-Markey, concluding that in 2020 the bill would cost the
average family only $160 a year, or 0.2 percent of income. That’s roughly the
cost of a postage stamp a day.
By 2050, when the emissions limit would be
much tighter, the burden would rise to 1.2
percent of income. But the budget office also predicts that real G.D.P. will be
about two-and-a-half times larger in 2050 than it is today, so that G.D.P. per
person will rise by about 80 percent. The
cost of climate protection would barely
make a dent in that growth. And all of this, of
course, ignores the benefits of limiting global warming.
So where do the apocalyptic warnings about the cost of climate-change
policy come from?
Are the opponents of cap-and-trade relying on different studies that reach
fundamentally different conclusions? No, not really. It’s
true that last spring the Heritage Foundation put out a report claiming that
Waxman-Markey would lead to huge job losses,
but the study seems to have been so obviously absurd that I’ve hardly seen
anyone cite it.
Instead, the campaign against saving the planet rests mainly on lies.
Thus, last week Glenn Beck — who seems to be challenging Rush Limbaugh
for the role of de facto leader of the G.O.P. — informed his audience of a
“buried” Obama administration study showing that Waxman-Markey would actually
cost the average family $1,787 per year. Needless to
say, no such study exists.
But we shouldn’t
be too hard on Mr. Beck. Similar — and similarly false — claims about the
cost of Waxman-Markey have been circulated by many supposed experts.
A year ago I would have been shocked by this
behavior. But as we’ve already seen in the health care debate, the
polarization of our political discourse has forced self-proclaimed “centrists”
to choose sides — and many of them have apparently decided that partisan
opposition to President Obama trumps any concerns about intellectual honesty.
So here’s
the bottom line: The claim that climate
legislation will kill the economy deserves the same disdain as the claim that
global warming is a hoax. The truth about the economics of climate change is
that it’s relatively easy being green.
It’s Easy Being Green,
NYT, 25.9.2009,
https://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/25/
opinion/25krugman.html
Related >
Anglonautes > Vocapedia
describing / talking about
language, actions, things,
facts, events, trends, ideas,
sounds, pictures, places,
people, personality traits, behaviour
English language
describing actions / thoughts,
iconic words,
translations / faux amis,
acronyms
Voir aussi > Anglonautes >
Grammaire anglaise explicative - niveau avancé
auxiliaires de modalité / modaux
be + -ing
|